|
|||||||||||||||||||
You have to look at the system of currency pegs--when a currency is tied to the dollar or to another hard currency. This
peg may not hold, but people assume that there is a fixed relationship between the dollar and, let's say, the Thai currency
or the Malaysian currency. They then exploit the difference in domestic interest rates and the international market. They
borrow in dollars and they lend in the domestic currency. They make a fortune in the process, as long as the peg holds. But
because of, maybe, excessive borrowing, which allows a country to maintain a trade deficit over an extended period of time,
or to engage in a currency or real estate boom financed by dollars, you have over-heating, trade imbalance, and then the capital
flows reverse. People want to take their money out, instead of putting it in, and you have a crisis.
You've written and spoken about the deeper trends that are going on in the financial markets today. Now, there is the prevailing theory which holds that financial markets should be regarded as if they were in continuous
equilibrium. I think that is actually a false image. Because, in effect, they are in continuous disequilibrium. Therefore,
they are given to going to excesses in one direction or another. You can have a boom and a bust. Now, in practice, we have
learned that that's the case. Through experience, we have evolved a system of central banking that prevents these excesses
from going too far. Controlling the money supply, dampening the boom so that you don't get a bust. Then stimulating the economy
[that] is in decline. You have various regulatory authorities and so on.
We now have global markets. We don't have an appropriate international mechanism for regulating the global financial markets.
That's a problem. We have the Bretton Woods Institutions--the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank. But they were
created for a different world, a world in which there were no capital movements. In fact, these institutions were designed
to make trade possible in the absence of international lending, and so on. These institutions adopted themselves to changing
circumstances.
You also had, at the time, fixed exchange rates. So the fixed exchange rate system broke down. Global capital markets developed.
The institutions, the IMF, is not adequate to meet these circumstances. It adapted itself and did reasonably well in one crisis
after another. There was a big international crisis in the '80s ... mainly focused in America. Then you had the Mexican crisis
in '94. Now, you had this latest crisis. Here, the IMF method proved to be inadequate. So their intervention became part of
the problem, instead of being part of the solution.
You criticize people who you called, "market fundamentalists." Tell me what their theory is, and why you're critical
of it.
Well, market fundamentalists recognize that the role of the state in the economy is always disruptive, inefficient, and
generally has negative connotations. This leads them to believe that the market mechanism can take care of all the problems.
Get the state out of there. The markets are perfect. In fact, they will take care of themselves.
The first part of the proposition is correct. The second part is false. Just because state intervention is imperfect, is
full of negative effects, doesn't mean that markets are either stable or provide social justice. Or are appropriate for certain
functions that society needs, but cannot be, in my opinion, provided by the market. So it's carrying the belief in markets
to an extreme, which is, I think, today very, very dangerous.
So do you think that the markets today have too much power?
Well, they are too influential. They have penetrated into areas of society where they weren't previously, or to a much
lesser extent. For instance, they have come to dominate the professions. Law has become a business. Health care has become
a business. Unfortunately, politics has also become a business. That really undermines society.
Since the middle of 1987, beginning in Thailand, it tends to be the countries, themselves, who are blamed by many for
the problems, for the crisis. You've seen some other unifying themes ...
That's right. I mean, of course, there is something wrong in the policies followed by those countries. But the crisis affected
a great number of countries, some of which followed very different kinds of policies. There is, however, a unifying theme.
That is the role of capital flows.
The capital flows themselves can be destabilizing. I mean, it's sort of an innate feature of markets. It's very good to
have capital flows, but you also have to recognize that they can be destabilizing. Therefore, you need some mechanism to prevent
them from creating these dislocations ...
As you said, you consider this situation quite dangerous.
Well, I do.
Why?
Well, so far, there have been tremendous economic dislocations, tremendous human suffering as a result of what happened
in financial markets, affecting what is now called innocent bystanders. Millions of people who are not entrepreneurs, who
hadn't made any decisions, didn't borrow foreign currency. A lot of them, rather poor people, who have actually benefited
over the years, in an improvement in their standard of living. Suddenly a collapse--losing their jobs, having much less income,
much higher prices, and so on. Losing their savings, in the case of currencies that collapse.
So tremendous dislocations. They have occurred in what I call the periphery of the global capitalist system. These are
the countries that have been attracting capital or using capital coming from abroad. It has, if anything, actually benefited
us and our economy, because we have had the benefit of cheaper imports. Its incipient inflationary tendency was nipped in
the bud. Actually, we were on the verge of perhaps having higher interest rates, which would have pushed us into a slow-down.
Because of the financial crisis, we actually got lower interest rates and a new shot of stimulus.
So we, if anything, benefited. It's very hard right now to convince people that there is something really wrong, because
they don't feel it themselves. But if they look abroad, they can certainly see it. In my view, there is a very good chance
that the next crisis, which may happen in the next few months, or the next new years ... we'll actually have a similarly or
maybe not quite as seriously disruptive effect, but a negative effect on our economy.
I say it's not going to be so serious because we gave a very effective institutional framework to guard against it. So
it's not likely to be as severe as it was, let's say, in Indonesia or Brazil. But nevertheless, it could have a negative effect
in our economy. If that were to happen before the rest of the world has recovered, then you would have a worldwide depression
similar to what happened in the 1930s.
Because if we began to have problems ...
Well, because, right now, people suffer some dislocations in our economy. People lose jobs, as we turn to cheaper imports
from Mexico or from other parts of the world. But there's tremendous new job creation. Actually, our unemployment is very
low. The economy is really very prosperous. We aren't overheating. It's probably the best of all possible worlds. But if you
now started to go into slowdown, and people who lost their jobs couldn't find new jobs, then the outcry against cheap imports
and the loss of jobs, would become politically much more powerful.
As it is, we are imposing some restrictions, for instance, on imports of steel, because they are, in fact, flooding our
market. That protectionist sentiment would then become much stronger. Then you would start disrupting international trade,
as a result of the disruption of financial markets. Then you would get into a problem that the countries that have to repay
their debts would not be able to earn the hard currency, which they need, in order to service their debts. So that you would
have financial distress, as well as interruption of trade.
... A lot of people marked the beginning of the current crisis is Thailand. But there are others who say that ... the
wrong lessons were learned in '94 and '95 in Mexico ...
Yes. Well, you see, what happened in '94-'95, Mexico had, again, a pegged exchange system, had a trade deficit, and a current
account deficit, and the peg couldn't be maintained. There was a crisis. The IMF, under the leadership of the Treasury came
in with a very large rescue package, which allowed Mexico to service its debt, the Treasury bills that it had issued, in dollars.
So the people who had invested in Mexico came out scot-free. That gave rise to what is considered the moral hazard--that it's
safe to invest, even in an unsound economy, because if things go wrong, the IMF and the Treasury is going to bail you out.
This is a particularly important factor in Russia, which was totally unsound, but people kept on lending money, because
they were convinced that Russia is so important geo-politically, that we wouldn't let them default. It turned out to be false.
But it led to this unsound lending and the moral hazard.
Opinion has turned very strongly against moral hazard now, which actually creates the opposite problem, that the IMF is
unable to come to the rescue, because if it did, it would be accused of bailing out the speculators and the unsound lenders.
So it's unable to come to the rescue. Therefore, it's very risky to lend, and nobody wants to lend. So you now have a situation
when there is a reverse flow of capital fleeing from the periphery, coming back to the center. Whereas, most of the remedies
that are proposed are remedies against excessive investments, excessive lending. The problem now is exactly the opposite ...
So what I am advocating is a more balanced approach, where you, on the one hand, do impose some penalties on people who
lend or invest in countries that are unsound. You make that clear in advance. This will discourage them from investing. You
prevent sort of unsound booms, but, at the same time, you must also create conditions that will encourage people to lend or
invest in countries which are in need of capital and are following sound policies. For that, the IMF has to develop into something
like a lender of last resort for those countries which are sound enough that it is appropriate to lend to them. Not to countries
that are broke. This would correct the imbalances which have developed.
The other thing that is wrong with the IMF policies is that they can only come in when there is a crisis. They really have
absolutely no standing until they are called in. They are only called in after a breakdown. Now, the best way to prevent a
bust is to moderate the boom. You really need to come in earlier and to follow the correct policies. So if you have the IMF
acting as a lender of last resort for countries that meet the right conditions, then the IMF can exert influence to prevent,
let's say, excessive borrowing, and so on. This would give you a more balanced system of rewards and punishments. Similar
to the position of a central bank, that actually sort of stimulates an economy, or dampens a boom, by changing the interest
rates. So that is the new architecture that you would need.
There is one major objection to this, that the distinction between good guys and bad guys is too rough. There is too much
discontinuity. That you actually have to create a more sort of nuanced rating of the countries, match the facilities that
you provide to the conditions in that country. That would then be a balanced system. So that is what I am, generally speaking,
proposing. It is being considered. But politically, the idea of making the IMF more powerful, especially after it has failed,
is a very difficult thing to sell ... the IMF has failed, because it didn't have adequate resources. I don't think that you
can have a global market without a lender of last resort, and something resembling a global central bank, which is what this
would, in fact, be.
In general, what are the reactions ... to your diagnosis? To your saying that there's something quite wrong here and
that we need some new rules.
I think that they are very much aware of it. In fact, some of their statements went a long way in that direction. When
they talked about preventive lending, that's what they were talking about. There is a danger that the calamity is not severe
enough, and hasn't touched us directly enough to gather the political will to do something about it. So the punitive or negative
aspects are moving forward.
For instance, there is discussion to change the nature of international bond contracts, so that it's easier to restructure
them and to delay payment. But the effect of that will be merely that people will demand a higher risk premium. So while all
these measures are useful, there has to be something on the positive side. That is where it's difficult to gather the political
will ... Especially, to gather the political will in the United States, where Congress is very much opposed to it.
Is the Treasury also opposed to it?
The Treasury is much more open minded. In other words, they are studying it, but they are aware of the political realities.
So while my ideas are being considered, I don't think they are considered very realistic.
When you, as an investor, as a trader, look out at the world, six months, nine months down the road, what kinds of things
are you looking for?
The financial markets generally are unpredictable. So that one has to have different scenarios ... The idea that you can
actually predict what's going to happen contradicts my way of looking at the market.
Actually, I see tremendous imbalance in the world. A very uneven playing field, which has gotten tilted very badly. I consider
it unstable. At the same time, I don't exactly see what is going to reverse it. Certainly, a slowdown in our economy would
leave the world extremely vulnerable, because the U.S. economy is, today, the single engine that is driving this very big
plane. So if that engine were to conk out, you'd have a very serious problem. It's a question [of], can you repair the other
engines before this one gives out. Because even though people say that we live in a new world, and the past is not relevant
... cyclical fluctuations are not eliminated. That's my main concern.
... I just want to clarify ... that what you have is a very uneven playing field. You have excess liquidity at the center
and a great deficiency of capital at the periphery. The money is still flowing from the periphery towards the center. So we
ought to find a way to inject liquidity in the periphery. Instead of that, we can only inject liquidity at the center. The
Federal Reserve can lower interest rates, and has done so.
What you need is a mechanism to provide capital to countries like Brazil, which is where money is fleeing. Interest rates
are very high. The country is going into recession. So this is what creates a tremendous imbalance, at the moment, which is
not sustainable. It could lead to ... if this engine now gives out, then you have a problem.
I mean, in fact, there is a certain danger that because of the injection of liquidity, our financial markets have become
overheated. You have signs of speculation, excessive speculation in areas like Internet stocks, and so on. You could conceivably
have at some point a crash that would then have negative effects on the real economy ... In this country. And then, indirectly,
on the rest of the world ...
Let's talk about Russia ... Is there any way that what happened there could have been moderated? That the fall could
have been not so severe?
Well, you see, it's really a tragic situation, because again, everything that could be done wrong, we have done wrong.
We have failed to provide the kind of aid that Russia would have needed, which would have been more in the nature of a Marshall
Plan or something more intrusive than the Marshall Plan was in Europe.
Instead of that, we left it to the IMF to provide support. The IMF deals with countries where the government promises to
fulfill certain conditions, and the IMF then lends them the money. But actually, in Russia, you did not have a functioning
central government. Therefore, they kept on promising, but they couldn't possibly deliver. So the IMF was actually the wrong
institution to be helping Russia, but we were not willing to put taxpayers' money at work. We gave it to the IMF, which had
its own resources, so we could do it costlessly.
That's the background. Now, gradually, Russia tried to change from this robber-capitalist system that prevailed, to something
more legitimate. Just at the time that the crisis came, they actually had the best government, the most honest, the most committed
to reform, who actually tried to do battle with the robber-capitalists, and tried to get them to pay their taxes.
The robber-capitalists then fought them. They controlled the media. They actually destroyed the reformers and created or,
let's say, coincided with the crisis. The IMF had a program which was unfortunately short on money. The deficiency was not
that great. I, at the time, estimated it to be $7 billion, which is really peanuts in this context.
I think that providing that extra money could have given that government, let's say, six months breathing space, during
which they could have proven whether they are, in fact, able to collect the taxes that they had to do. So, it would have been
a very small price to pay. But for various reasons, the international community didn't come through.
You then had a collapse, effectively a default, which shook markets. The government immediately fell. You now live in a
kind of a twilight period, when things are drifting. You have a government that has proven itself quite good in sort of holding
things together, so that cushioning the rate of decline, but not showing any ability to turn things around.
So you just have a deteriorating situation. Also, a kind of a political vacuum. You have a drift. There's very little you
can do right now, except to hold the door open. Try to avoid an official default that would isolate Russia, in a way that
would be quite dangerous. Wait for some kind of political resolution, and the emergence of a government with whom one could
work towards more active reform.
How do they get out of it, when essentially, they have no money?
Well, they can't. They don't get out. They get out of it by not using money, actually. You see, practically everything
is done by barter. So, as far as money is concerned, they are broke. But since the economy doesn't use money, it kind of grinds
along. I mean, it's very inefficient. Barter is much more inefficient than a monetary economy, but it doesn't totally break
down. It was not a mistake, because it's the only thing they could do. As long as people were willing to lend to them, it's not
a mistake to borrow, when you are broke. I would say that any observer could see that the whole situation is unsound and unsustainable.
The only question was whether they could actually start implementing the reforms which they were promising ... The tragedy
was that ... in the spring of '98, they started raising the cost of electricity and collecting taxes ... Then they got involved
in this fight with the so-called oligarchs, the robber-capitalists, which preoccupied them, and the reform effort kind of
fell by the wayside. Then came the global crisis. Through hook and crook, they managed to get a new government in place which
was, actually, as I say, a very good government. But it had no chance to see whether they can actually deliver on their promises.
... That new, reformist prime minister said the first numbers that he was shown showed that what they owed to repay
their debts was billions of dollars more than they were bringing in.
Correct. Right.
I mean, from day one of his ...
There was a hole, actually ... You see, the IMF plan assumed that the maturing treasury bills will be rolled over or can
be rolled over, even if the interest rate is atrociously high. That [at] some interest rate, there will be some buyers. But
what they've left out of account is that the holders of the GKOs were banks that borrowed dollars to buy the GKOs, couldn't
repay the dollars. The foreign banks were not willing to lend them any more money. So they could not roll over the GKO at
any price. So there was a hole there. As the Russian public started withdrawing its savings from the national savings bank,
the hole got bigger. What started out as a hole of $7 billion, within a week or two became a hole of $15 billion. Would have
even become bigger.
So you began to understand that they were in deep trouble ... What did you think was going to happen? ...
Well, you see, I made probably the worst miscalculation of my investment career, because I invested in the Russian telephone
company, in the expectation that they were going to make this transition from robber-capitalism to legitimate capitalism.
Then it would have been a very good investment. They turned to me and wanted to borrow some money against the next tranche
of the telephone company to be privatized. That prompted me to look at the situation. I realized that it was beyond redemption.
Except through another additional [loan] package. I thought at first that it could perhaps be put together as a public-private
partnership.
Then, when the situation got worse, I concluded the only way would have been to introduce a currency board and stabilize
the situation. So right up to the last minute, the situation could have been at least temporarily stabilized, but it would
have been a very, very high risk. Lending money to people who have consistently failed to deliver on their promises, in the
hope that this time they'll do better. So the political risk of throwing good money after bad was just too much, with a very
hostile Congress. With Germany preoccupied with the elections, and Chancellor Kohl didn't want to deal with this issue at
all. There was no support from Germany. So it was impossible to put a package together.
You wrote a famous letter that was published in The Financial Times, when you proposed this currency board, but
you also said that people did not understand the urgency of the situation ...
Well, you see, I wrote a letter to The Financial Times, proposing a currency board. As part of the currency board,
a 15%-25% devaluation, which would have been necessary, because the currency had become overvalued. Also, would have taken
into account this moral hazard problem, because people who had invested in the local Treasury bills would have lost at least
15%-25% of their money. So I thought that that was necessary. Unfortunately, people didn't understand what a currency board
was, but they understood what devaluation was. I then got blamed for the collapse of the market, which actually is somewhat
unjustified, because it would have collapsed without my letter, but it just happened to coincide with the collapse.
What would have happened if Russia had devalued back in the spring? Back in April, May?
I think it would have helped.
... Tell me something about that last weekend, before Monday, the 17th of August ... of the feelings that were going
on in your conversations with people.
Well, it was clear to all parties concerned that this was a crisis of the greatest magnitude. There were a number of conversations
about what could be done. I know of an international conference call among the G-7 countries, who discussed this issue. But,
as I said before, no package could be put together. Whereupon, the Russians took it up on themselves to act unilaterally.
That really shocked the market, because it was effectively a unilateral default. The shock then reverberated through the
financial markets. Banks became very anxious about their outstanding loans. Certain relationships between different markets,
which had been sort of moved way out of normal. At the same time, you had a number of hedge funds, investment banks that had
speculated on those relationships going back to normal. They had large positions, which normally turned out to be profitable.
At this time, disparities, the divergences, just grew out of all proportion, since these operations are carried on with very
high leverage meaning that it's all done with borrowed money.
There was a hedge fund, Long Term Capital Management ... this entity lost a lot of its capital ... The banks started asking
for additional collateral, which they didn't have. There was tremendous danger that if these positions had to be liquidated,
then the disparities would get even bigger. Not only would the Long Term Capital Management be unable to meet its obligations,
but a lot of the banks, and investment banks, that had lent to Long Term Capital, and also had similar positions in their
own proprietary trading debts, would also be called up on to liquidate their positions.
So you would have sort of an avalanche of selling, where you wouldn't know who is a good counterpart and who isn't. You
wouldn't know which institution is solvent and which is broke. That would have been a meltdown of the financial markets. That
would have then had a devastating effect on credit all around.
Seeing it develop, the New York Fed intervened, and got the major counterparties of Long Term Capital Management to put
in addition capital. So that they didn't have to liquidate their positions. That move prevented this meltdown.
You've written that not only were you disappointed in the response of the G-7 countries to the Russian crisis, but that
there was a loss of control, as you've called it, that was quite scary. Can you tell me what you meant by that?
... Well, the consequences of this unilateral default showed up in the market, where there was a flight to safety. The
normal relationship between lower grade bonds and high grade government bonds, widened. The stock market was shaken and started
to fall. We actually came very close to what I call a meltdown of the system, as a result of the problems connected with Long
Term Capital Management.
So, not only was it, let's say, a reasonable gamble, to give some additional support to Russia, in order to help Russia
from a breakdown, but it also would have saved us from that particular incident.
Now, the Fed was more effective in intervening in the domestic market, than the G-7 was intervening internationally. So
the worst outcome was avoided. The effect on Russia, we have seen. But actually, the effect on the financial markets proved
to be very transient.
The Russians were basically told by Monday morning, August 17th, that they were on their own, that nothing was going
to be put together.
Yeah. I think that on Sunday, they were told. They went to Yeltsin, and got his consent for this default action. So Sunday
night, it was announced Monday morning, it was a fait accompli.
You lost a bunch of money in Russia.
Yes. Yes.
You said it was the worst investment decision in your life.
Right. Right ...
Do you think people understand the seriousness of what happened in Russia, that there are still potential repercussions?
I think that people generally realize the situation is pretty hopeless right now. It's probably not quite as hopeless as
it seems to us, who have sort of orderly minds, and we want to see ... Russia seems to be able to get by.At the time, a lot
of people were aware how serious the internal situation was. That's why the markets fell. But it was a temporary panic. Through
the intervention of the Fed, bailing out Long Term Capital Management, and very shortly thereafter, lowering interest rates,
which was a very important move--markets took heart. It's now sort of like an episode that's almost forgotten.
But shouldn't be?
Well, it should not be forgotten, because these kinds of episodes are liable to reoccur. No reform will ever eliminate
the risk of some kind of a breakdown. But when you identify what has gone wrong and what could be done to fix it, you actually
do need to fix it. Because without it, we couldn't have developed the financial markets we have.
Financial markets have always failed from time to time. Then, they got fixed by some advance in central banking or in a
regulatory environment. As a result, financial markets got increasingly sophisticated, refined and effective. If you now allow
this belief that markets are best left alone to predominate and refuse to fix the deficiencies, then you run the really serious
risk that you will have a very serious breakdown. home | timeline | will it happen again? | interviews | russia | solutions web site copyright 1995-2005 wgbh educational foundation TO RETURN TO THE FACTS THE BROKERS, AND THE FINANCIAL REPORTERS, WONT TELL YOU! PAGE |
|||||||||||||||||||
There are always opportunities through which businessmen can profit handsomely if they will only recognize and seize them. J. Paul Getty (1892 - 1976)
|
|||||||||||||||||||